Is monetary policy alone enough to stimulate economic recovery?

comments 0

Comment

share

Share

0

Rate

Aurodeep Nandi's picture

Consider an allegory1.

Say there is a dying garden that needs revival. You figure out that it needs watering. You connect a suitably long garden-hose to the nearby tap, and continue watering the plants for some time. The garden however refuses to show any improvement.

The policy questions then can be threefold.

Q1. Is there something wrong with the hosepipe? Or else you could infinitely go on turning the tap and the plants still wouldn‟t be receiving the desired quantity of water. (Are the channels of monetary transmission reliable?)

Q2. Can the garden recover alone on water? Are there other things too that need to aid its recovery? (Is monetary easing alone enough for recovery?)

Q3. If the garden isn‟t recovering, then will flooding it with water solve its problems? (Is ‘more’ monetary easing the key to a slowdown?)

Does turning on the tap necessarily ensure mean that the garden is being watered?

The god of monetary policy works (or does not!) in mysterious ways...

For one, it depends on what kind of economy it is operating in. For a developing country like India, the relevance of central bank policy rates came only with the reforms and liberalization in 1990‟s that introduced market determined rates to the economy. Infact till 1997, the RBI2 was expected to automatically monetize the government‟s fiscal deficit, effectively creating inflationary pressures at the behest of the government! India finally passed an act on fiscal responsibility as late as 20033.

Hence the effectiveness of monetary transmission in assisting recovery in a developing economy depends crucially on the maturity of its reforms.

The developed economy case is no less complex. The success of monetary policy then becomes vulnerable to the vagaries of the economy. As a simple example, suppose the dominant channel of monetary transmission for a small open economy is through exchange rates – low policy rate weakening the currency; hence encouraging exports (increasing output) and making imports expensive (increasing inflation). But during a crisis if the country is unable to keep its export sector competitive or its domestic demand for imports falters; then the rationale of lowering policy rates stands defeated.

Similarly a crisis that clogs potential monetary transmission channels like the banking system, or the housing market, or financial markets; can severely impair the effectiveness of monetary policy. These institutions would need repairing; which may not be entirely in the central bank‟s mandate. At best it could support markets by purchasing private sector assets to reduce risk premiums and improve liquidity.

And finally, monetary policy will be impotent for an economy opting for fixed exchange rate and open capital account; as per the celebrated „Impossible Trinity‟. Hong Kong finds itself on such a vertex. However real world experiences have shown that the assumptions behind the trinity are often too simplistic to hold. A number of East-Asian economies in the past decade have been able to maintain open capital markets and partially manage their exchange rate; while enjoying relatively independent monetary policy4.

Does watering the garden really help?

It is really interesting to once again draw parallels with an emerging market. In India, real GDP growth slowed down from 8.4% in FY5 2011 to an expected 6.9% in FY 20126. Fiscal stimulus will be suboptimal since India is already saddled with high fiscal deficit. The RBI, that had tightened policy rates by around 525 basis points since 2010; is now expected to reverse gears. Monetary policy here is explicitly being used to cure growth slowdown.

In many ways, economists will argue that this is precisely what the proverbial „Macroeconomics 101‟ course trained them to expect. Central banks should try to bring down long term interest rates by lowering policy rates. The basic idea behind quantitative easing is also to ultimately reduce yields, and increase expected inflation. In the process, ex-ante real interest rate, (nominal interest rate adjusted for expected inflation) ought to fall below the equilibrium rate7 for the economy, and hence stimulate aggregate demand.

But in the case of developed nations, the liquidity trap makes this theory just too good to be true! In a liquidity trap, the central bank has already reduced nominal policy rate to zero levels. But the dismal economic outlook causes people to rather hold onto cash than financial securities, effectively checkmating conventional monetary policy. The much debated „monetary‟ escape route out of the trap is for it to be expansionary enough to change public‟s perception of future inflation and interest rates. Ultimately it is the central bank telling the public that it is willing to tarnish its reputation of maintaining low inflation; till growth has credibly improved.

But if the panacea is to raise inflationary expectations...then why doesn’t the government simply raise the prices of some goods and services?

Supply side pressure on prices will easily translate into demand side inflation. More importantly, the general rise in prices should have a rapid effect on inflationary expectations...and voila, the issue is solved!

Somehow this assails common sense! How can low demand be stimulated by higher prices8?! Many would say that it reminds them of stagflation in the UK of the 1970‟s – a trap of low growth and high inflation. The funny thing is that high global commodity prices currently are building inflationary pressures in advanced economies. UK‟s CPI (Consumer Price Index) has been rising above 3% (y/y) since 2010 while US‟ CPI has risen from 1% in mid-2010 to around 3% currently9. And the magnanimous quantitative easing that these economies are currently conducting will ensure that inflation remains elevated going forward.

Hence real interest rates ought to be lower now than they would have been in the case of outright deflation. However aggregate demand doesn‟t seem to be responding to these reduced real rates. Wherein lies a partial rebuttal to the argument of exogenously raising prices – the whole idea behind lowering real interest rate is to inspire business and consumer confidence, and hence lead to increase in aggregate demand. Heightened prices alone do not solve the issue.

So too much of water doesn’t work?

Will consumers spend; businesses make investments; and banks increase lending, if interest rates are low enough. During a crisis, businesses are likely to be influenced more by the absence of demand and banks, by the risk of lending; than the low cost of funds. This could explain why much of the excess liquidity from quantitative easing has been channeled into fuelling rallies in commodities and taking speculative positions on currencies, than productively increasing lending to businesses and consumers. Infact the excess liquidity in the system effectively bails out risk takers, creates perverse incentives for debt accumulation, and creates risk for future inflation.

Or is it that equilibrium real rate is too low?

Reducing the real interest rate is basically to get it below the equilibrium rate. But suppose it is too low to begin with? The equilibrium real interest rate is theoretically determined by the intersection of an upward sloping savings curve and downward sloping investment curve. Higher consumption (and hence lower savings) raises the rate. So does a pickup in productivity growth and increase in working age population (which will increase investment demand). During a crisis people become more inclined to save; hence leading to drop in the equilibrium rate. Fiscal spending is meant to effectively counter the dis-saving of the private sector. Much of it is beyond the ambit of conventional central banking.

So simply dump monetary policy?

Suppose central banks hadn‟t reacted at all to the current crisis? For one, higher policy rates would ensure that aggregate spending to be much lower that it is presently. Also the absence of excess liquidity would keep credit spreads high in key markets causing systemic financial instability. Strains in financial markets would then spill over to the broader economy; which in turn would generate even greater market uncertainty; hence creating adverse feedback loops10.

Final prognosis: gardening can be very difficult!

The essay tries to analyze the possible challenges facing monetary policy if it had to stimulate the recovery alone. The first stop for diagnosis was the channels of monetary transmission. The essay evidences how their effectiveness varies with the economic and regulatory milieu. Next the essay shifts from the channels to the concepts of monetary policy. It argues that the stimulating demand through lowering real interest rates is not at all straight-forward. Especially with the target equilibrium rate being determined by a host of non-monetary factors. But does all this mean that expansionary monetary policy is completely useless under an economic slowdown?

The romantic-at-heart essayist feels that the importance of loved ones is best realized in their absence! The same also goes for monetary policy. Only that you can‟t sustain just on love!

References: 
  1. An extended metaphor wherein a story illustrates an important attribute of the subject.
  2. Reserve Bank of India, India‟s central bank.
  3.  The FRMB (Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management) Act, enacted by the Indian Parliament in 2003.
  4. The „Impossible Trinity‟ has voluminous academic literature to its credit, which is beyond the scope of the topic. A couple of papers where the point raised in the essay, has been highlighted include: Grenville, S. 2011. “The Impossible Trinity and Capital Flows in East Asia.” ADBI Working Paper No. 319. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute; Patnaik, I., and A. Shah. 2010. “Asia Confronts the Impossible Trinity.” ADBI Working Paper 204. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute.
  5. Fiscal Year (April – March)
  6. Advance estimates from the Government of India.
  7. There is considerable literature on what qualifies as measures for real rates and more importantly „equilibrium‟ real rates. We progress with the essay assuming that they can be suitably defined for an economy.
  8. Incidentally Tobin had first suggested in 1972 that a small amount of inflation could help „grease the wheels‟ of the economy since workers like to see rise in nominal wages. On the other hand, zero inflation with downward wage rigidity, could potentially lead to higher unemployment. Numerous academic studies have followed trying to either dispute the claim, or quantify the extent of „grease‟ required!
  9. Similar trends observed in core CPI (ex-food and fuel) inflation for the US and the UK.
  10. Also referred to as the financial accelerator. [Bernanke, Ben S., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist. 1996. “The Financial Accelerator and the Flight to Quality,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 78: 1-15.; Bernanke, Ben S., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist. 1999. “The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework,” in John B. Taylor and Michael Woodford, eds., Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. 1, part 3. Amsterdam: North-Holland: 1341-93.]
  11. Auerbach, Alan J., and Maurice O., (2003), ”The Case for Open-Market Purchases in a Liquidity Trap,” working paper, University of California, Berkeley.
  12. Agell, Jonas, and Mats P., “Does Debt Management Matter?” in J. Agell, M. Persson, and B.M. Friedman, Does Debt Management Matter? Oxford: Claredon Press, 1992.
  13. Benhabib, Jess, Stephanie S., and Martin U., “The Perils of Taylor Rules,” Journal of Economic Theory 96: 40-69 (2001).
  14. Bernanke, Ben S., Jean B., and Piotr E (2005). "Measuring the Effects of Monetary Policy: A Factor-Augmented Vector Autoregressive (FAVAR) Approach," Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 120, no. 1, pp. 387-422.
  15. Bernanke, Ben S., Gertler M., and Gilchrist S., (1996). “The Financial Accelerator and the Flight to Quality,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 78: 1-15.
  16. Bernanke, Ben S., Gertler M., and Gilchrist S., (1999). “The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework,” in John B. Taylor and Michael Woodford, eds., Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. 1, part 3. Amsterdam: North-Holland: 1341-93.
  17. Boivin J., and Giannoni Marc P., (2006). "Has Monetary Policy Become More Effective?" Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 88, no. 3, pp. 445-462.
  18. Brock, William A., “Money and Growth: The Case of Long-Run Perfect Foresight,” International Economic Review 15: 750-777 (1974).
  19. Buiter, Willem H., and Nikolaos Panigirtzoglou, “Liquidity Traps: How to Avoid Them and How to Escape Them,” in Wim F.V. Vanthoor and Joke Mooi, Reflections on Economics and Econometrics: Essays in Honour of Martin M.G. Fase, De Nederlandsche Bank, 2001.
  20. Calvo, Guillermo A. (1983), “Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 12: 383-98.
  21. Card, D. and Hyslop D., (1997), “Does Inflation Greases the Wheels of the Labor Market?" in Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy, C. Romer and D. Romer, eds., Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
  22. Cecchetti, Stephen G., (2003), “Central Banks have Plenty of Ammunition,” Financial Times, March 17, p. 13.
  23. Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gali and Mark Gertler (1999), “The Science of Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian Perspective,” Journal of Economic Literature 37: 1661-1707.
  24. Fehr, E. and L. Goette, (2005), “Robustness and Real Consequences of Nominal Wage Rigidity," Journal of Monetary Economics 52, pp. 779-804.
  25. Frankel, J., “Portfolio Crowding-Out Empirically Estimated,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 100: 1041-1066 (1985).
  26. Fair, Ray C. (2004), Estimating How the Macroeconomy Works. Harvard University Press.
  27. Friedman, Benjamin M. (1989) Changing Effects of Monetary Policy on Real Economic Activity, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Symposium Proceedings
  28. Friedman, Milton (1957) A Theory of the Consumption Function (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1957).
  29. Galí, Jordi, and Luca Gambetti (2009) On the Sources of the Great Moderation. American Economic Journals-Macroeconomics.
  30. Galí, Jordi, David Lopez-Salido and Javier Valles (2003) ''Technology Shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed's Performance'', Journal of Monetary Economics , vol. 50 (May 2003), pp. 723-743.
  31. Gertler, M. and Gilchrist, S. (1993) " The Role of Credit Market Imperfections in the Monetary Transmission Mechanism: Arguments and Evidence," Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Blackwell Publishing, vol. 95(1), pages 43-64.
  32. Gertler, M. and Gilchrist, S. (1994) "Monetary Policy, Business Cycles, and the Behavior of Small Manufacturing Firms," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, MIT Press, vol. 109(2), pages 309-40, May.
  33. Gertler, M. and Nobuhiro K., (2010) Financial Intermediation and Credit Policy in Business Cycle Analysis, This Volume. Gilchrist, Simon, Alberto Oriz, and Egon Zakrajsek (2009) Credit Risk and the Macroeconomy:
  34. Grenville, S. 2011. “The Impossible Trinity and Capital Flows in East Asia.” ADBI Working Paper No. 319. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute
  35. Gürkaynak, Refet S., Brian S. and Eric S. (2005) "The Sensitivity of Long-Term Interest Rates to Economic News: Evidence and Implications for Macroeconomic Models," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 95(1), pages 425-436, March.
  36. Hall, Robert E. (1988) Intertemporal Substitution in Consumption. The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 96, No. 2 (Apr., 1988), pp. 339-357.
  37. Hanushek, Eric A., Quigley John M., (1980) What is the Price Elasticity of Housing Demand? The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 62, No. 3 (Aug., 1980), pp. 449-454
  38. Harrison, R, Nikolov, K, Quinn, M, Ramsay, G, Thomas, R and Scott, A (2005) The Bank of England Quarterly Model, Bank of England.
  39. Hatzius, J. (2005). “Housing Holds the Key to Fed Policy,” Goldman Sachs Global Economics
  40. Paper No. 137 (New York: Goldman Sachs, February)
  41. Kashyap, Anil K. & Stein, Jeremy C., (1995). "The impact of monetary policy on bank balance sheets," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Elsevier, vol. 42(1), pages 151-195, June.
  42. Kiley, Michael T. (2010) Output Gaps. Federal Reserve Board Finance and Economics Discussion Series.
  43. Lettau, M. and Ludvigson Sydney C., (2004) "Understanding Trend and Cycle in Asset Values: Reevaluating the Wealth Effect on Consumption," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 94(1), pages 276-299, March.
  44. Lucas, Robert (1976). "Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique". Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 1: 19–46.
  45. Mauskopf, E. (1990). "The Transmission Channels of Monetary Policy: How have they Changed?" Federal Reserve Bulletin, vol. 76, no. 12, pp. 985.
  46. Meh, Césaire and Moran K., (2008) "The Role of Bank Capital in the Propagation of Shocks," Working Papers 08-36, Bank of Canada.
  47. Miron, Jeffrey A., Romer Christina D. and Weil David N., (1994) "Historical Perspectives on the
  48. Monetary Transmission Mechanism," in N.G. Mankiw, ed. Monetary Policy, pages 263-306 National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
  49. Mishkin, Frederic S. (1976) "Illiquidity, Consumer Durable Expenditure, and Monetary Policy,"
  50. American Economic Review, 66 No. 4 (September): 642-654.
  51. Mishkin, Frederic S. (1978), "The Household Balance-Sheet and the Great Depression," Journal
  52. of Economic History 38 (December 1978): 918-937.
  53. Mishkin, Frederic S. (1995). "Symposium on the Monetary Transmission Mechanism," Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 3-10.
  54. Mishkin, Frederic S. (2007). "Housing and the Monetary Transmission Mechanism," Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Housing, Housing Finance, and Monetary Policy, 2007 Jackson Hole Symposium (Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City). pp. 359-413.
  55. Mishkin, Frederic S. (2008), “Global Financial Turmoil and the World Economy,” speech given at the Caesarea Forum of the Israel Democracy Institute, Eliat, Israel, July 2, 2008,
  56. Mundell, R.A. (1963), "Capital Mobility and Stabilization Policy under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates", Canadian Journal of Economics 29: 475-485.
  57. Murchison, Stephen and Andrew Rennison (2006) "ToTEM: The Bank of Canada's New Quarterly Projection Model," Technical Reports 97, Bank of Canada.
  58. Patnaik, I., and Shah, A. (2010). “Asia Confronts the Impossible Trinity.” ADBI Working Paper 204. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute.
  59. Peek, Joe, and Rosengren, E., (1995a) “The Capital Crunch: Neither a Borrower nor a Lender Be Source”: Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 27, No. 3 (Aug., 1995), pp. 625-638
  60. Peek, Joe, and Rosengren, E., (1995b). "Is bank lending important for the transmission of monetary policy? An overview," New England Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, issue Nov, pages 3-11.
  61. Peek, Joe, and Rosengren, E., (1997) “The International Transmission of Financial Shocks: The Case of Japan.” The American Economic Review, Vol. 87, No. 4 (Sep., 1997), pp. 495-505.
  62. Peek, Joe, and Rosengren, E., (2010) “The Role of Banks in the Transmission of Monetary Policy”, in The Oxford Handbook of Banking, Allen Berger, Philip Molyneux, and John Wilson, eds. (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
  63. Primiceri, G. (2005) "Why Inflation Rose and Fell: Policymakers' Beliefs and US Postwar Stabilization Policy," NBER Working Papers 11147, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
  64. Ramey, Valerie A. (1993) How Important is the Credit Channel in the Transmission of Monetary Policy?," NBER Working Papers 4285, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
  65. Romer, Christina D. and Romer D., (1989) "Does Monetary Policy Matter? A New Test in the Spirit of Friedman and Schwartz," NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1989, Volume 4, pages 121-184 National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
  66. Sims, Christopher A. and Tao Zha (2006) "Were There Regime Switches in U.S. Monetary Policy?," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 96(1), pages 54-81, March.
  67. Smets, F. (1995) “Central bank macroeconometric models and the monetary policy transmission mechanism”, in: BIS (1995), Financial structure and the monetary policy transmission mechanism, C.B. 394, March.
  68. Smets, F. and Rafael W. (2007) "Shocks and Frictions in US Business Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 97(3), pages 586-606, June.
  69. Tobin, J., (1972), “Inflation and Unemployment," American Economic Review 62, pp.1-18